In
economics,
money illusion, or
price illusion, refers to the tendency of people to think of currency in
nominal, rather than real, terms. In other words, the numerical/face value (nominal value) of money is mistaken for its
purchasing power (real value) at a previous point in the general price level (in the past). This is false, as modern
fiat currencies have no intrinsic value and their real value is derived from all the underlying value systems in an economy, e.g., sound government, sound economics, sound education, sound legal system, sound defence, etc. The change in this real value over time is indicated by the change in the
Consumer Price Index over time.
The term was coined by
Irving Fisher in
Stabilizing the Dollar. It was popularized by
John Maynard Keynes in the early twentieth century, and
Irving Fisher wrote an important book on the subject,
The Money Illusion, in 1928.
[1] The existence of money illusion is disputed by
monetary economists who contend that people act rationally (i.e. think in real prices) with regard to their wealth.
[2] Eldar Shafir,
Peter A. Diamond, and
Amos Tversky (1997) have provided
empirical evidence for the existence of the effect and it has been shown to affect behaviour in a variety of experimental and real-world situations.
[3]
Shafir et al.
[3] also state that money illusion influences economic behaviour in three main ways:
Money illusion can also influence people's perceptions of outcomes. Experiments have shown that people generally perceive an approximate 2% cut in nominal income with no change in monetary value as unfair, but see a 2% rise in nominal income where there is 4% inflation as fair, despite them being almost rational equivalents. This result is consistent with the 'Myopic Loss Aversion theory'.
[4] Furthermore, the money illusion means nominal changes in price can influence demand even if real prices have remained constant.
[5]
Explanations and implications[edit]
Explanations of money illusion generally describe the phenomenon in terms of
heuristics. Nominal prices provide a convenient rule of thumb for determining value and real prices are only calculated if they seem highly
salient (e.g. in periods of
hyperinflation or in long term contracts).
Some have suggested that money illusion implies that the negative relationship between inflation and unemployment described by the
Phillips curve might hold, contrary to more recent
macroeconomic theories such as the "expectations-augmented Phillips curve".
[6] If workers use their nominal wage as a reference point when evaluating wage offers, firms can keep real wages relatively lower in a period of high inflation as workers accept the seemingly high nominal wage increase. These lower real wages would allow firms to hire more workers in periods of high inflation.
See also[edit]
References[edit]
- Jump up^ Fisher, Irving (1928), The Money Illusion, New York: Adelphi Company
- Jump up^ Marianne Bertran, Sendhil Mullainathan, and Eldar Shafir (May 2004). "A behavioral-economics view of poverty". The American Economic Review 94 (2): 419–423. doi:10.1257/0002828041302019. JSTOR 3592921.
- ^ Jump up to:a b Shafir, E.; Diamond, P. A.; Tversky, A. (1997), "On Money Illusion", Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (2): 341–374, doi:10.1162/003355397555208
- Jump up^ Benartzi, Shlomo; Thaler, Richard H. (1995). "Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle". Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (1): 73–92. JSTOR 2118511. edit
- Jump up^ Patinkin, Don (1969), "The Chicago Tradition, The Quantity Theory, And Friedman", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 1 (1): 46–70, JSTOR 1991376
- Jump up^ Romer, David (2006), Advanced macroeconomics, McGraw-Hill, p. 252, ISBN 9780072877304
Further reading[edit]
- Fehr, Ernst; Tyran, Jean-Robert (2001), "Does Money Illusion Matter?", American Economic Review 91 (5): 1239–1262, doi:10.1257/aer.91.5.1239, JSTOR 2677924
- Howitt, P. (1987), "money illusion", The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics 3, London: Macmillan, pp. 518–519, ISBN 0-333-37235-2
- Weber, Bernd; Rangel, Antonio; Wibral, Matthias; Falk, Armin (2009), "The medial prefrontal cortex exhibits money illusion", PNAS 106 (13): 5025–5028, doi:10.1073/pnas.0901490106, PMC 2664018, PMID 19307555
- Akerlof, George A.; Shiller, Robert J. (2009), Animal Spirits, Princeton University Press, pp. 41–50
- Thaler, Richard H.(1997) "Irving Fisher: Modern Behavioral Economist" in The American Economic Review Vol 87, No 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1997)
- Huw Dixon (2008), New Keynesian Economics, New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics New Keynesian macroeconomics.
No comments:
Post a Comment